What Is the Money Supply?

The U.S. coin supply comprises currency—dollar bills and coins issued past the Federal Reserve Organisation and the U.S. Treasury—and various kinds of deposits held by the public at commercial banks and other depository institutions such as thrifts and credit unions. On June 30, 2004, the coin supply, measured equally the sum of currency and checking account deposits, totaled $1,333 billion. Including some types of savings deposits, the coin supply totaled $half dozen,275 billion. An even broader measure totaled $nine,275 billion.

These measures correspond to three definitions of money that the Federal Reserve uses: M1, a narrow measure of money'southward office as a medium of exchange; M2, a broader measure out that too reflects coin'south function as a store of value; and M3, a still broader measure that covers items that many regard every bit close substitutes for money.

The definition of money has varied. For centuries, physical commodities, most usually silver or gold, served as money. Later, when paper coin and checkable deposits were introduced, they were convertible into commodity money. The abandonment of convertibility of money into a commodity since August 15, 1971, when President Richard M. Nixon discontinued converting U.S. dollars into gilt at $35 per ounce, has made the monies of the United States and other countries into fiat money—money that national monetary authorities have the power to issue without legal constraints.

Why Is the Money Supply Important?

Considering coin is used in virtually all economic transactions, it has a powerful effect on economic activity. An increase in the supply of coin works both through lowering involvement rates, which spurs investment, and through putting more money in the hands of consumers, making them feel wealthier, and thus stimulating spending. Business organisation firms respond to increased sales past ordering more raw materials and increasing production. The spread of business activity increases the demand for labor and raises the demand for capital letter appurtenances. In a buoyant economic system, stock marketplace prices ascent and firms consequence disinterestedness and debt. If the money supply continues to aggrandize, prices begin to rise, especially if output growth reaches capacity limits. As the public begins to await inflation, lenders insist on higher involvement rates to offset an expected refuse in purchasing power over the life of their loans.

Opposite furnishings occur when the supply of money falls or when its charge per unit of growth declines. Economical activity declines and either disinflation (reduced inflation) or deflation (falling prices) results.

What Determines the Money Supply?

Federal Reserve policy is the virtually important determinant of the coin supply. The Federal Reserve affects the money supply by affecting its about important component, bank deposits.

Here is how it works. The Federal Reserve requires depository institutions (commercial banks and other financial institutions) to hold every bit reserves a fraction of specified deposit liabilities. Depository institutions hold these reserves every bit cash in their vaults or Automatic Teller Machines (ATMs) and equally deposits at Federal Reserve banks. In turn, the Federal Reserve controls reserves by lending money to depository institutions and changing the Federal Reserve disbelieve rate on these loans and past open up-market operations. The Federal Reserve uses open up-market place operations to either increase or subtract reserves. To increase reserves, the Federal Reserve buys U.Due south. Treasury securities by writing a check drawn on itself. The seller of the treasury security deposits the cheque in a banking company, increasing the seller's deposit. The bank, in turn, deposits the Federal Reserve check at its district Federal Reserve bank, thus increasing its reserves. The reverse sequence occurs when the Federal Reserve sells treasury securities: the purchaser'due south deposits autumn, and, in turn, the banking concern's reserves fall.

If the Federal Reserve increases reserves, a single depository financial institution can brand loans up to the amount of its backlog reserves, creating an equal corporeality of deposits. The banking system, however, tin can create a multiple expansion of deposits. Equally each depository financial institution lends and creates a deposit, it loses reserves to other banks, which use them to increase their loans and thus create new deposits, until all excess reserves are used upward.

If the required reserve ratio is x percent, then starting with new reserves of, say, $1,000, the nearly a bank can lend is $900, since it must keep $100 equally reserves confronting the deposit it simultaneously sets upwardly. When the borrower writes a check confronting this amount in his bank A, the payee deposits it in his banking company B. Each new demand deposit that a bank receives creates an equal amount of new reserves. Bank B volition now have additional reserves of $900, of which it must proceed $90 in reserves, and so it can lend out but $810. The full of new loans the banking system equally a whole grants in this instance volition be ten times the initial amount of excess reserve, or $9,000: 900 + 810 + 729 + 656.1 + 590.v, and so on.

In a organisation with partial reserve requirements, an increase in banking company reserves can back up a multiple expansion of deposits, and a decrease tin result in a multiple contraction of deposits. The value of the multiplier depends on the required reserve ratio on deposits. A high required-reserve ratio lowers the value of the multiplier. A depression required-reserve ratio raises the value of the multiplier.

In 2004, banks with a total of $seven meg in checkable deposits were exempt from reserve requirements. Those with more $7 million merely less than $47.half dozen million in checkable deposits were required to go along 3 per centum of such accounts as reserves, while those with checkable accounts amounting to $47.6 million or more were required to keep ten percent. No reserves were required to be held confronting time deposits.

Even if there were no legal reserve requirements for banks, they would still maintain required clearing balances as reserves with the Federal Reserve, whose ability to control the volume of deposits would not be dumb. Banks would continue to keep reserves to enable them to articulate debits arising from transactions with other banks, to obtain currency to meet depositors' demands, and to avoid a deficit every bit a result of imbalances in clearings.

The currency component of the money supply, using the M2 definition of money, is far smaller than the eolith component. Currency includes both Federal Reserve notes and coins. The Lath of Governors places an order with the U.S. Agency of Engraving and Printing for Federal Reserve notes for all the Reserve Banks and then allocates the notes to each district Reserve Bank. Currently, the notes are no longer marked with the individual district seal. The Federal Reserve Banks typically concur the notes in their vaults until sold at confront value to commercial banks, which pay private carriers to pick up the greenbacks from their district Reserve Depository financial institution.

The Reserve Banks debit the commercial banks' reserve accounts as payment for the notes their customers demand. When the demand for notes falls, the Reserve Banks accept a return catamenia of the notes from the commercial banks and credit their reserves.

The U.S. mints pattern and manufacture U.S. coins for distribution to Federal Reserve Banks. The Board of Governors places orders with the appropriate mints. The system buys coin at its face value past crediting the U.S. Treasury's account at the Reserve Banks. The Federal Reserve System holds its coins in 190 coin terminals, which armored carrier companies ain and operate. Commercial banks buy coins at face value from the Reserve Banks, which receive payment by debiting the commercial banks' reserve accounts. The commercial banks pay the total costs of shipping the coin.

In a fractional reserve banking system, drains of currency from banks reduce their reserves, and unless the Federal Reserve provides adequate boosted amounts of currency and reserves, a multiple contraction of deposits results, reducing the quantity of money. Currency and bank reserves added together equal the monetary base, sometimes known every bit high-powered coin. The Federal Reserve has the power to control the issue of both components. By adjusting the levels of banks' reserve balances, over several quarters it can reach a desired rate of growth of deposits and of the coin supply. When the public and the banks modify the ratio of their currency and reserves to deposits, the Federal Reserve can offset the effect on the coin supply past changing reserves and/or currency.

If the Federal Reserve determines the magnitude of the money supply, what makes the nominal value of money in existence equal to the amount people desire to agree? A change in interest rates is 1 mode to make that correspondence happen. A autumn in interest rates increases the amount of coin people wish to concur, while a ascension in interest rates decreases that corporeality. A modify in prices is some other way to make the money supply equal the corporeality demanded. When people agree more nominal dollars than they want, they spend them faster, causing prices to rise. These ascent prices reduce the purchasing power of money until the amount people desire equals the corporeality available. Conversely, when people concord less money than they want, they spend more than slowly, causing prices to autumn. Every bit a event, the real value of coin in being simply equals the amount people are willing to hold.

Irresolute Federal Reserve Techniques

The Federal Reserve's techniques for achieving its desired level of reserves—both borrowed reserves that banks obtain at the discount window and nonborrowed reserves that information technology provides by open-market purchases—accept changed significantly over time. At get-go, the Federal Reserve controlled the volume of reserves and of borrowing past member banks mainly by irresolute the discount rate. It did so on the theory that borrowed reserves made fellow member banks reluctant to extend loans considering their desire to repay their own indebtedness to the Federal Reserve as shortly as possible was supposed to inhibit their willingness to accommodate borrowers. In the 1920s, when the Federal Reserve discovered that open-market operations also created reserves, irresolute nonborrowed reserves offered a more than effective way to get-go undesired changes in borrowing past member banks. In the 1950s, the Federal Reserve sought to control what are chosen free reserves, or excess reserves minus fellow member bank borrowing.

The Fed has interpreted a ascent in interest rates as tighter budgetary policy and a fall every bit easier monetary policy. Merely involvement rates are an imperfect indicator of monetary policy. If easy monetary policy is expected to crusade inflation, lenders demand a higher involvement charge per unit to compensate for this inflation, and borrowers are willing to pay a higher rate because inflation reduces the value of the dollars they repay. Thus, an increase in expected inflation increases interest rates. Between 1977 and 1979, for instance, U.S. budgetary policy was easy and interest rates rose. Similarly, if tight monetary policy is expected to reduce inflation, involvement rates could fall.

From 1979 to 1982, when Paul Volcker was chairman of the Federal Reserve, the Fed tried to control nonborrowed reserves to accomplish its monetary target. The procedure produced big swings in both money growth and interest rates. Forcing nonborrowed reserves to pass up when above target led borrowed reserves to rise considering the Federal Reserve allowed banks admission to the disbelieve window when they sought this alternative source of reserves. Since then, the Federal Reserve has specified a narrow range for the federal funds charge per unit, the interest charge per unit on overnight loans from i bank to another, equally the instrument to reach its objectives. Although the Fed does not straight transact in the Fed funds market, when the Federal Reserve specifies a higher Fed funds charge per unit, it makes this higher rate stick by reducing the reserves it provides the unabridged financial arrangement. When it specifies a lower Fed funds rate, it makes this stick past providing increased reserves. The Fed funds market place charge per unit deviates minimally from the target charge per unit. If the deviation is greater, that is a indicate to the Fed that the reserves information technology has provided are not consistent with the funds charge per unit it has announced. It volition increase or reduce the reserves depending on the departure.

The large change in Federal Reserve objectives under Alan Greenspan's chairmanship was the acknowledgment that its primal responsibility is to command inflation. The Federal Reserve adopted an implicit target for projected future inflation. Its success in meeting its target has gained it brownie. The target has become the public'south expected aggrandizement rate.

History of the U.S. Money Supply

From the founding of the Federal Reserve in 1913 until the end of Globe State of war Two, the money supply tended to abound at a higher rate than the growth of nominal GNP. This increase in the ratio of coin supply to GNP shows an increase in the amount of money every bit a fraction of their income that people wanted to hold. From 1946 to 1980, nominal GNP tended to grow at a higher charge per unit than the growth of the coin supply, an indication that the public reduced its coin balances relative to income. Until 1986, money balances grew relative to income; since then they accept declined relative to income. Economists explain these movements by changes in cost expectations, likewise every bit by changes in interest rates that make money property more or less expensive. If prices are expected to fall, the inducement to concur coin balances rises since money will purchase more if the expectations are realized; similarly, if interest rates autumn, the cost of holding money balances rather than spending or investing them declines. If prices are expected to rising or involvement rates rising, holding coin rather than spending or investing it becomes more than plush.

Since 1914 a sustained reject of the coin supply has occurred during just three business bike contractions, each of which was severe as judged past the decline in output and ascension in unemployment: 1920–1921, 1929–1933, and 1937–1938. The severity of the economic decline in each of these cyclical downturns, information technology is widely accepted, was a issue of the reduction in the quantity of money, particularly so for the downturn that began in 1929, when the quantity of money fell by an unprecedented one-third. There have been no sustained declines in the quantity of money in the past six decades.

The United States has experienced three major toll inflations since 1914, and each has been preceded and accompanied by a corresponding increase in the rate of growth of the money supply: 1914–1920, 1939–1948, and 1967–1980. An acceleration of coin growth in backlog of existent output growth has invariably produced inflation—in these episodes and in many earlier examples in the United States and elsewhere in the globe.

Until the Federal Reserve adopted an implicit inflation target in the 1990s, the money supply tended to rise more apace during business concern cycle expansions than during business cycle contractions. The rate of ascent tended to autumn before the peak in business organisation and to increase before the trough. Prices rose during expansions and roughshod during contractions. This pattern is currently not observed. Growth rates of money aggregates tend to be moderate and stable, although the Federal Reserve, like most primal banks, now ignores coin aggregates in its framework and practice. A possibly unintended issue of its success in controlling aggrandizement is that coin aggregates have no predictive power with respect to prices.

The lesson that the history of coin supply teaches is that to ignore the magnitude of money supply changes is to court budgetary disorder. Time will tell whether the electric current monetary nirvana is enduring and a challenge to that lesson.


About the Author

Anna J. Schwartz is an economist at the National Bureau of Economic Research in New York. She is a distinguished fellow of the American Economic Association.


Further Reading

Eatwell, John, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, eds. Coin: The New Palgrave. New York: Norton, 1989.

Friedman, Milton. Monetary Mischief: Episodes in Monetary History. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1992.

Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. A Budgetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton Academy Press, 1963.

McCallum, Bennett T. Budgetary Economic science. New York: Macmillan, 1989.

Meltzer, Allan H. A History of the Federal Reserve. Vol. 1: 1913–1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Printing, 2003.

Rasche, Robert H., and James Yard. Johannes. Controlling the Growth of Monetary Aggregates. Rochester Studies in Economies and Policy Issues. Boston: Kluwer, 1987.

Schwartz, Anna J. Money in Historical Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Printing, 1987.